Friday, April 19, 2024

Miller Association should heed CCPC’ advice before the Competition Law scotches the Association

Share

mealie meal3

By Simon Ng’ona

Business Associations (BAs) can play a productive, pro-competitive role in the development of a particular sector, thus promoting the efficient functioning of that market. BAs, which consist of individuals and firms with common interests in trade, join together to further their commercial or professional goals. Although the principal function of a BS, typically, is to provide services to its members, these associations also have industrial policy and political functions.
BAS frequently perform many valuable functions, and these are elucidated in a number of scattered literature. Through cooperation, BAS can significantly increase the efficiency and performance of a particular sector. Nevertheless, collaboration between otherwise competing firms raises the possibility that cooperation may overflow into coordination, thus lessening competition between these firms or in the market more generally. Consumer harm, in the form of raised prices or lower quality goods or services, is the almost inevitable consequence of such collusion. In a number of instances globally, moreover, BAs have played a central role in the management of a cartel among their members.

On various occasions, the Competition Consumer Protection Commission (CCPC), even in its old outfit as Zambia Competition Commission (ZCC, has encountered, in the course of its enforcement activities, varied situations. Many media articles and annual reports for the Commission, at least those that are in public domain, suggest that where BAs have coordinated, or have been used as a vehicle by which to coordinate, the activities of member firms, the consequence has been that competition between member firms is restricted. In light of these experiences, the Competition Authority has continued to raise specific concerns regarding activities of BAs and their compliance with competition law.
One contemporary issue relate to the Millers Association of Zambia (MAZ). The latter’s recent quest to hike Mealie Meal prices has receive resistant, hostility and squashing responses from varying stakeholders including Government, Consumer Organisation and others.

In as much as the Millers, just like other industry players, are facing both productive and supply side challenges due the economic paralysis Zambia is in, it is business immorality for the association to continue setting prices. This practice has been a tendency by most associations and this is a situation that cannot be allowed to pervade the exiting free market economic setup and requirements.

This abridged article provides information and brief guidance for BAswhich coordinate at horizontal level and their members regarding competition dynamics and price fixing. It provides information about the limits that competition law places on joint or coordinated action by competitors.

Prohibition of price setting and the motives behind it;

Within the category of coordinated activities, it is firmly established that there arecertain practices which are absolutely prohibited, such as price-fixing, as well as many practices which may have an anticompetitive effect,and are thus prohibited. Mr Hanford Chaaba, the Public Relations officer at the CCPC, in his recent statement, draws the public and the MAZ to Section 8 of the Competition and Consumer Protection Act (CCPA) 2010. Despite him not detailing the particulars of this Section in his statement as quoted by media, he has given us the specific provision and individually we can inquire more on what this Section says.

Section 8. says…… “Any category of agreement, decision or concerted practice which has as its object or effect, the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition to an appreciable extent in Zambia is anti-competitive and prohibited”. …..

This Section and the subsequent ones prohibit and make void all decisions taken by associations of undertakings, as well as agreements and concerted practices between undertakings, which have either the object or the effect of preventing, restricting or distorting competition.

But what does competition in the purview of literature and practice mean. To get a clear understanding on whether effective competition has ensued or not, two variables will always have to be factored in mind i.e price and non-price competition.Non-price competition is a form of competition among suppliers where they try to win customers not by lowering prices but by improving their product brand and advertising, offering after-sales-service, using sale promotion tools, etc. On the other hand, Price Competition is a form of competition among suppliers where the suppliers try to win customers by offering them a product at a price which is lower than their competitor’s price.

These two factors collectively form what might be termed as effective competition, although they can be looked at isolatedly. Therefore, any effort to undermine either of the two factors through concerted efforts or price fixing is prohibited under most competition laws.In short, competition law prohibits any coordinated activity between competing firms which lessens the normal uncertainty that should exist between them in relation to pricing policies arrived at independently on the market. Thus, firms are prohibited from entering into agreements which restrict the freedom of the contracting parties in relation to pricing in any way.

But I must admit that, the concept of consented efforts is given a very wide interpretation under the case law that has evolved over time. Discussing case law that has ensued on this particular subjectis outside the scope of this article. However, I will explore the possibility of writing another article on the same.

Moving forward, what could be some of the decisions that could warrant prohibition under competition law? As already indicated, these include, not merely formal decisions adopted by an association under any procedures laid down in its constitution or founding documents, but also the constitution itself, any rules governing the association’s operations, binding regulations made by the association and any nonbinding recommendations made by it, for as long as they are it is distorting effective competition.I am tempted to wonder whether the commission has done anlegal audit of some of the constitutions governing these associations and vet whether there are provisions which promote anti-competitive behaviour. If not, this could be one potential area of work the commission could explore. More importantly, since the CCPA is under review, it is important to include such explicit provisions than leaving it to wider interpretation.

The latter part of the preceding sentence shows that the concepts of agreement and concerted practice among business associations can be been interpreted widely. Agreements can also include unwritten agreements and gentlemen’s agreements as well as formal contracts for as long as they are promoting anti- competitive practice and restrictive business behaviour. The CCPA in Section 9, exemplify a similar situation through definition of a horizontal agreement. “a horizontal agreement between enterprises is said to be prohibited per se, and void, if the agreement; (a) fixes, directly or indirectly, a purchase or selling price or any other trading conditions; (b) divides markets by allocating customers, suppliers or territories specific types of goods or services”. If one closely looks at these potential violations as provided in the Act, the major source for such violations could be through consented practices in associations. Note:these are not the only provisions that relate to this issue.

Now that the law is clear, why has the MAZ eschewed heeding advice from the Commission? Or why has MAZ opted to ignore such provisions and continue to announce prices instead of leaving it to individual players. This applies to all business associations.

Having raised this, I have a premonition that some players or indeed mother associations will be scolding my statement. However, these are facts ladies and gentlemen and legally backed by the current legal framework.

But anyway, could there be any exemption for associations to engage under competition law. The Zambian competition law and others acknowledges that cooperation between associations may, in certain instances; result in some benefits to consumers. If cooperation does not appreciably restrict, prevent or distort competition in the first place, it will fall entirely outside the prohibitions contained in PART III of the CCPA which deals with restrictive business and anti-competitive trade practices. Section 8 and 9 highlighted above are under Part III and goes way till section 23. Please, dear Bas, read these provisions and empower your members with such information. Otherwise, you have no authority to hike price and as Mr Chaaba has indicated, your announcement has triggered anxiety and panic buying among consumers.

The Author is the Centre Coordinator for Consumer Unity and Trust Society (CUTS) International Lusaka. (Dip Journ and PR; BA – Economics; LLM – Trade and Investment Law)

8 COMMENTS

  1. CCPC is as inept as ACC! Business is Business! If you don’t know the difference between capital and profit, you should not be in business! Our Miller’s need protection. Government has been reckless and that is what CCPC should have been addressing!

  2. Millers should charge whatever price they want but buyers should buy at the price they can afford. If mealie meal is not selling then millers will know that the price is too high. PF and their CCPC have no say in this. Only bakachema who grow crops should comment. PF should only talk about salaula prices because that is the only trade they respect in Zambia. Aki mbonyi ya maho!

    • prices. Competition only exists going into town (e.g from kabulonga) and it is because of this competition that you pay lower prices.

      So from this one can see that at 4k the bus operators are able to operate profitably on this route and thus the correct price for the route really is 4k the 2k is the excess they get when competition is limited and it is us the consumers paying for this excess.

      This is the same scenario evolving when you allow these so called associations (MAZ) to operate. Such associations should be prohibited by law.

  3. What kind of profit appetite, nay, greed is this? Increasing mealie meal prices when there’s no shortage of maize stocks, it’s simply inexcusable. This is capitalism without a human face.

    • prices. Competition only exists going into town (e.g from kabulonga) and it is because of this competition that you pay lower prices.

      So from this one can see that at 4k the bus operators are able to operate profitably on this route and thus the correct price for the route really is 4k the 2k is the excess they get when competition is limited and it is us the consumers paying for this excess.

      This is the same scenario evolving when you allow these so called associations (MAZ) to operate. Such associations should be prohibited by law.

  4. All these associations should be banned I don’t understand this nonsense they limit competition and where there’s no competition the consumer always suffers.

    My fellow commentaries let me illustrate the importance of competition with the example of minibuses. Do you understand why is it that you always have to pay a fixed high price when you board a bus from the station (kulima tower)?

    For example for a someone coming from town going to kabulonga the fixed price is k6 and you can’t pay any less but coming from kabulonga going into town the price varies and you can pay as low as 4k.

    This is because at the station they is no amount of competition and you don’t have a choice which bus you board, the suppliers effectively have a cartel in operation enabling them to charge…

  5. All these associations should be banned I don’t understand this nonsense they limit competition and where there’s no competition the consumer always suffers.

    My fellow commentaries let me illustrate the importance of competition with the example of minibuses. Do you understand why is it that you always have to pay a fixed high price when you board a bus from the station (kulima tower)?

    For example for a someone coming from town going to kabulonga the fixed price is k6 and you can’t pay any less but coming from kabulonga going into town the price varies and you can pay as low as 4k.

    This is because at the station they is no amount of competition and you don’t have a choice which bus you board, the suppliers effectively have a cartel in operation enabling them to charge higher…

  6. prices. Competition only exists going into town (e.g from kabulonga) and it is because of this competition that you pay lower prices.

    So from this one can see that at 4k the bus operators are able to operate profitably on this route and thus the correct price for the route really is 4k the 2k is the excess they get when competition is limited and it is us the consumers paying for this excess.

    This is the same scenario evolving when you allow these so called associations (MAZ) to operate. Such associations should be prohibited by law.

Comments are closed.

Read more

Local News

Discover more from Lusaka Times-Zambia's Leading Online News Site - LusakaTimes.com

Subscribe now to keep reading and get access to the full archive.

Continue reading